Processing math: 100%
“Be kind, for everyone you meet is fighting a hard battle” - Often attributed to Plato but likely from Ian McLaren (pseudonym of Reverend John Watson)

Friday, April 25, 2025

More $Trump memecoin


 The way a meme coin typically works is:

  1. Someone achieves some notoriety for something, or exploits some notoriety they already have. They seek to monetize this notoriety.
  2. They use one of any number of meme coin generators and choose a blockchain.
  3. They generate a pot of, say, ten million coins, and release, say, four million onto the block chain with a LOT of fanfare and a lot of, basically, b.s. about building a community, adding value, etc. They keep the other six million coins. The reputable thing to do is to "lock up" most or all of the six million coins for some period. If they simply sell into the initial wave of buyers and walk away, this is known as a "rug pull" and, while it's considered unseemly at best and results in a ton of howling and shedding of crocodile tears, this is often what happens. See &Hawk for a good example.
  4. As the lockup period's end approaches, the originators have to create some additional fanfare to drive the price up or back up.
  5. The originators sell into the market at the increased price.
  6. End of story - a bunch of people have a bunch of worthless meme coins, less money, and a sad story to tell. The originators have a bunch of money and can move on to the next scam event.
In essence, this is the story of the $Trump con coin. There is a lockup period end coming, the price of the coins has declined, so the Trump organization needs some razzle dazzle around the coins. So, to boost demand, Trump will be hosting an "intimate private dinner," for the top "220 Special $Trump Meme Coin Holders" (as shown on a "leader board,") that is, in order to have dinner with the President, you must have or purchase sufficient $Trump coins to be in the top 220 holders. For the top 25, there is a reception and White House tour. Clearly. a great way for the Trump organization to boost the price into which they sell their locked up coins, and a great way for Trump sycophants supporters to bribe him throw cash his way. Note that the coin rose some 60% in "value" after the dinner was announced.

In very small print, we see "This Tour is being arranged by Fight Fight Fight LLC. President Trump is appearing at the dinner as a guest and not soliciting any funds for it." No, he needn't do so since the increase in value of the coins his organization holds will provide plenty of cash.

It's always been obvious that Trump is completely lacking in any moral compass or sense of right and wrong (at least where his own behavior is concerned, he's certainly willing to lash out at others). I wouldn't have thought, though, that he could continuously reach new depths of self-serving behavior.

As I quoted someone in my previous $Trump coin blog post, we voted for corruption, and Trump is delivering. As MAGAVoice constantly prattles on X, née Twitter, "Promises made, promises kept."

Tuesday, April 15, 2025

More on "epsilon" in the "Reciprocal Tariffs" equation

 


In the equation published by the Office of the U.S. Trade Representative* (\Delta\tau_{i}=\frac{x_{i}-m_{i}}{\varepsilon*\varphi*m_{i}}), we see the Greek letter \varepsilon, epsilon. This number is stated to be the elasticity of import demand with respect to import prices. An economist would call this the "price elasticity of demand (PED)", a number which represents the rising and falling of demand with the falling and rising of prices.

The actual definition is that the PED at a given point on the supply and demand curve  is the percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in price (\frac{\%\Delta\text{Q}_{d}}{\%\Delta\text{P}}).


Let's toss in some numbers and see what this means. Suppose that, at an existing aggregate price for widgets of $100,000,000.00 there are 1,000,000 widgets demanded. Next, suppose the PED is -4. Then \frac{\%\Delta\text{Q}_{d}}{\%\Delta\text{P}}=-4. Then suppose, as a result of a price increase due to tariffs, the price of widgets increases by 10%. Arranging the equation above, \%\Delta\text{Q}_{d}=-4\%\Delta\text{P}=-40\%. That is, a 10% increase in price will result in a 40% decrease in demand.

In thinking about whether this is reasonable, we need to consider the actual items being evaluated. For example, a Type 1 diabetic relies on insulin to stay alive, and hence must pay whatever the cost is for insulin. This is referred to as "demand being inelastic." On the other hand, it's likely that a significant increase in the price of, for example, iPhones will reduce demand, since new iPhones are not a necessity. This is referred to as "demand being elastic."

There are many considerations that go into PED. These include individual choices, availability of substitutes, the length of time a price increase has been in place (more time gives a greater time to search for substitutes), and others.

Whether it's stated as such or not, the "Reciprocal Tariffs" equation is intended specifically to reduce trade deficits. A larger \varepsilon in the equation will reduce the magnitude of the fraction and imply smaller tariffs, a smaller \varepsilon will do the opposite.

However, a "one size fits all" policy doesn't make a lot of sense. Some of our imports could, in theory, be replaced with domestic products (e.g., automobiles, microchips, etc.) while others could not (e.g., coffee, cobalt, bananas). Going back to Malaysia from my previous post, top U.S. imports are electrical and electronic equipment and machinery, nuclear reactors, and boilers. These items total about 71% of our imports and are among the categories that could, in principle, be produced domestically, though at considerably higher cost.

As examples, the PED for coffee in the U.S. is estimated to be 0.25 (quite inelastic, gotta have that caffeine!), that of fresh tomatoes is estimated to be 4.6 (very elastic). Note that economists typically utilize the absolute value of PED, that is, only showing its magnitude.

With this information, it's quite clear that, on top of the analysis of non-tariff trade barriers shown on the Trump Reciprocal Tariff chart and the rationalization on the U.S. Trade Representative's web page*, the numbers have little, if any, relation to the actual trade situation or to any deep analysis of price elasticity.

Ps: I guess I do have to thank Trump for getting me reengaged with blogging!

*As noted in my previous post, the page with the equation and the explanation has disappeared, or at least been moved to where I can't find it. If someone can find it and post a link in the comments, that would be great. Also as I alluded to, given all the mockery and derision the chart and the equation have engendered, I'd be embarrassed and ashamed as well.

Tuesday, April 08, 2025

Reciprocal Tariffs?


I'm wrapping my head around the equation stated by the Office of the President of the United States Trade Representative for calculating the so-called "Reciprocal Tariffs." * From that site, we see the following:\Delta\tau_{i}=\frac{x_{i}-m_{i}}{\varepsilon*\varphi*m_{i}}. We're told that \Delta\tau_{i} is the "change in the tariff rate"; x_{i} is "total exports to country i" (that is, U.S. exports); m_{i} is "total imports from country i" (that is, U.S. imports); \varepsilon is the "elasticity of imports with respect to import prices" (an economics concept measuring how much demand goes up or down when prices go down or up, but it can be ignored here because the next term cancels it out); and \varphi is the pass through from tariffs to import prices (this is the term that cancels out the elasticity term since the latter is stated to be 4 and the former is stated to be 0.25, thus totaling 1). Finally, since "we are a kind people," the derived number is divided by two to determine the final "reciprocal tariff."

Multiple sites characterize this as "trade deficit divided by total imports." It took me a moment to understand this, because trade deficit is imports minus exports, whereas the numerator of the fraction is exports minus imports, the negative of the deficit. But the site states that "\varepsilon\lt0," so the denominator is negative and, lo and behold, it all works out as described.

The chart above has three columns: Country (more on that later); "Tariffs Charged to the U.S.A. Including Currency Manipulation and Trade Barriers"; and "U.S.A. Discounted Reciprocal Tariffs" (calculated as above). One might reasonably infer from these column labels that, for each country, an analysis was done of the tariffs on U.S. exports in place along with currency manipulation and trade barriers to determine the number, but no. The site linked above states that:

While individually computing the trade deficit effects of tens of thousands of tariff, regulatory, tax and other policies in each country is complex, if not impossible, their combined effects can be proxied by computing the tariff level consistent with driving bilateral trade deficits to zero. If trade deficits are persistent because of tariff and non-tariff policies and fundamentals, then the tariff rate consistent with offsetting these policies and fundamentals is reciprocal and fair.

That is, in lieu of the above analysis, the fraction calculated in accordance with the equation above is used as a proxy. Note the "If." If my mother had wheels, she'd be a bus.

Now, with the background out of the way, let's stipulate that the general concept of there being a strong relationship between trade barriers imposed by countries receiving U.S. exports and the trade deficit with such countries as a fraction of U.S. imports from those countries is not completely irrational. In essence, this is a theory that trade is only fair with any given country if the balance of trade with that county is $0.00 and that "reciprocal tariffs" are the fair way to force this equilibration. I do not agree with this stipulation, but let's proceed nevertheless. Does the fraction calculated per the above reasonably capture this?

Let's start with an easy one. We'll take Malaysia as an example. In 2024, the U.S. imported $52.5B in goods from Malaysia and exported $27.7B in goods to Malaysia. Using the equation, the imputed "tariffs" would then be 47.2% and we "kindly" will only reciprocate with a 24% tariff. But Malaysia's population is 35.13 million, that of the U.S. is 340.1 million, almost 10 times as large. So, to "balance trade," each Malaysian would have to purchase \frac{340.1}{35.13}=\$9.68 for every dollar of Malaysian goods purchased by Americans. Clearly, this makes zero sense.

Instead then, let's see how things change if we use per capita numbers. Then we have \frac{\$52.5\text{ Billion}}{340.1\text{ million}}=\$154 dollars of U.S. imports per capita and \frac{\$27.7\text{ Billion}}{35.13\text{ million}}=\$788 in Malaysian imports per capita (that is, U.S. exports). That is, each Malaysian (on average) imports $788 of U.S. goods per year, while each member of the U.S. population imports a measly $154 of Malaysian goods per year. What happens if we use the per capita numbers in the equation? Then we have \frac{154-788}{154}=-431\%. Trump constantly rails about the U.S. being "ripped off" by our trading partners. But, using the silly logic described in the block quoted section, I have to ask "who's ripping off whom?"

Another aspect of the naive calculation as presented is the fact that, for example, the median annual household income in the U.S. (2023 figure) is $78,538. That of a Malaysian is $1,419. Is it reasonable to expect a Malaysian to purchase as much in U.S. goods as a U.S. resident purchases Malaysian goods? I don't think anyone could justify a "yes" answer (with the possible exception of Peter Navarro). But can we consider an adjustment to the equation to capture this as we did with the per capita trade quantities as above?

We could consider dividing the U.S. import number by the U.S. household income, that would yield imports per dollar of income. Similarly, we could divide Malaysia's import of U.S. goods by Malaysian household income. This would have even a more dramatic effect on the fraction. Taking both population and household income together would show that we're absolutely pillaging Malaysia!

There are other categories of countries and entities as well. Let's think about some countries with more in common with the U.S. If we consider the so-called "developed" countries, e.g., European Union, United Kingdom, Japan, South Korea, Norway, Australia, New Zealand, etc. and normalize them all similarly, what do we see?

I ran the per capita numbers for these countries and the results were:


Note that, on a per capita basis, every country (or entity in the case of the EU) shows a negative number, with the exception of the EU. That is, each nominal resident of the foreign country purchases, on average, more U.S. goods than a nominal U.S. resident does of theirs. 
The EU's positive number is a bit higher than calculated by Trump, et al, on a per capita basis. The EU's population significantly exceeds ours. But again, who is ripping off whom?

Were I to go through and utilize household income, the results would be even more stark, but this post is already excessively long. But I do want to say a bit more about Peter Navarro. Navarro, who is now the Senior White House Counselor for Trade and Manufacturing in the Trump Administration is, at best, a fringe economist. Among other hilarities, in books and articles, he quotes "Harvard economist Ron Vara" in support of his policies. You'll note that Ron Vara is an anagram of Navarro, and Navarro has conceded that Vara is purely fictional.

I want to cite a couple of sites. Matt Parker, of Stand Up Maths, explains the calculations and some of their faults and, finally, Coyote Blog expresses a viewpoint very much aligned with my own with respect to what I'll call the "philosophy of tariffs."

* Apparently, The Office of the U.S. Trade Representative has decided that it's best not to try to explain the so-called "Reciprocal Tariffs." The equation and its purported explanation are no longer there, at least that I can find. I'd have been embarrassed too. 


Friday, April 04, 2025

Howard Lutnick and Econ 101


Our esteemed Commerce Secretary, Howard Lutnick, stated in an interview on CBS that 
“You have to sort of understand how things work. When tariffs come into place, foreign goods may become a little more expensive, but domestic goods do not.”

Interesting. I’m no economist, but I have taken a couple of econ courses and read a bit. And, in studying the fundamental aspects of supply and demand, I encountered supply and demand curves. Searching the deep recesses of my memory and then scribbling on my phone, I produced the following:


Crude at best, but the point is valid. The solid lines represent price vs. quantity demanded and quantity supplied. They cross at a point referred to as the "equilibrium point," that is, the point at which the quantity demanded by buyers at that price matches the quantity willing to be supplied by producers. 
If the quantity demanded (the "demand curve") shifts to the right, the equilibrium price rises along with the quantity supplied.

Here, we're looking at domestic goods. Because the prices of imported goods are expected to rise significantly due to tariffs (Trump's claim that these will be paid by the exporting countries notwithstanding), demand for domestic goods can be expected to rise as buyers look for substitutes (another fairly basic concept from Econ 101). That is, the demand curve will shift to the right. This inevitably leads to increased production of domestic goods (which Trump, Lutnick, et al champion) but it does not do so without also increasing the price of those goods.

Now, Lutnick graduated from Haverford College in 1983 with a degree in economics. I don't imagine such a degree is conferred without learning about this concept. From that, we can infer a couple of things: 1) Lutnick is quite willing to lie; and 2) He likes his position as Secretary of Commerce. Saying Trump is incorrect while occupying a position he appointed is not a way to keep that position.

Clearly, there are vast complexities beyond the scope of this very simple analysis, but just because something is simple does not mean that it's wrong.